!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*() ------------------------------------------------------------ SMART Letter #85 -- March 4, 2003 Copyright 2003 by David S. Isenberg isen.com - "turkey" isen@isen.com -- http://isen.com/ -- 1-888-isen-com ------------------------------------------------------------ !@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*()!@#$%^&*() CONTENTS > How to Monopolize the New Network > Quotes of Note + Dick Cheney on "Noise in the System" + Tom Ridge on "Noise in the System" + Paul Wolfowitz on "Noise in the System" > If it's Funny, it Must Be True, by Scatt Oddams > Conferences on my Calendar > Copyright Notice, Administrivia ------- How to Monopolize the New Network by David S. Isenberg What's the business context that brings the New Network? Competition? Sorry, we can't get there from here, and even if we could, we'd be up against Googin's Paradox (that the best network is the hardest one to make money building and running, see http://netparadox.com/netparadox.html). Is regulation the best route to realizing our networked potential? Nah. Stuck in the past, Byzantine, for insiders only, not responsive to innovation in these times of great change. So, maybe, hypothetically, pure hands-off no-holds-barred unregulated monopoly, despite its ugliness, will bring the most connectivity soonest. The wise old marketplace has seen trouble -- exuberance, oversupply and bust -- many times before. 1865, for example, was a euphoric year in Oil Creek, Pennsylvania. It had been six years since Edwin Drake triggered an instant oil boom by showing the world that oil wells could be drilled and oil could be pumped to the surface. By 1865, "the wild drive to produce created in the Oil Regions [of Pennsylvania] a chaotic scene of heaving populations, of shacks and quick-built wooden buildings . . . of derricks and storage tanks, with everyone energized by hope and rumor and the acrid scent of oil" [_The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money & Power_ by Daniel Yergin, Simon & Schuster, New York, 1991, p. 32-33.]. At the time, oil had one big application -- kerosene for lighting. Kerosene gave better light than candles. It was a lot cheaper than whale oil. In the twelve months after Drake drilled the world's first oil well, some 15 refineries sprang up in Western Pennsylvania. "Kerosene of widely varying quality was sold. If the kerosene contained too much flammable gasoline or naptha, as sometimes happened, the purchaser's attempt to light it could be his last act on this earth" [ibid, p. 40]. The market for kerosene did not develop apace production. "Toward the end of the 1860s, as overproduction caused prices to plummet . . . the new industry went into a depression. The reason was simple -- too many wells and too much oil . . . between 1865 and 1870 the retail price of kerosene fell by more than half . . . refining capacity was three times greater than the market's needs . . . The 1870s were to be marked by ever-rising production. Producers repeatedly tried to restrict production, but to no avail. Storage tanks overflowed, covering the land in black scum. The gluts became so large and prices fell so low that crude oil was run out into streams and onto farms because there was nowhere else to put it. At one point, the price [which had been as high as $13.75 in the mid- 1860s] dropped to forty-eight cents a barrel." [ibid, p. 39- 42]. Standard Oil was so named because it brought standards to the production of kerosene; Standard's kerosene would not explode. Guided by the business vision of John D. Rockefeller, Standard Oil created insider deals with railroads to get rebates on its oil transportation costs. Unbelievably, Standard Oil also negotiated "drawbacks," which the railroads paid to Standard Oil for oil transport by non-Standard refineries. The control of oil transport costs gave Rockefeller's Standard Oil an insurmountable advantage. Rockefeller wanted to end glut-and-bust. His aim was to eliminate competition, "that cut-throat policy of making no profits," and control production to "make the oil business safe and profitable" [John D. Rockefeller's own words, ibid, p. 42]. It took him a mere 14 years. By 1879, Standard Oil controlled 90% of the refineries, and it dominated oil production, railroads, pipelines, the supply of oil barrels, and (some said) the legislatures of Pennsylvania and New York. The public was not delighted that Rockefeller's monopoly sold safe kerosene and brought an end to the glut and-bust era -- the Sherman Anti-Trust Act of 1890 was written in direct response to Standard's "powerful, devious, cruel, entrenched, all-pervasive and yet mysterious" monopoly muscling [ibid, p. 96]; Standard itself was convicted under Sherman in 1909 and broken up. However, it cannot be denied that monopoly has an upside; a robust and orderly oil business developed under the Standard banner. Nor can it be argued that monopoly is always against the interests of its customers; the first 60 years of the Bell System gave the United States the best telephone system in the world. Nor can it be argued that a marketplace with multiple competitors is free of criminally anti-customer behavior. If John D. Rockefeller were alive today, he would be building fiber to the home (FTTH). Fiber has so much capacity that once FTTH were built, there would never be a need for a second fiber. The builder of the fiber could tell the telephone company, "Hey, why bother to maintain that expensive copper-based distribution network? I'll carry those telephone signals to your customers for less than it costs you to maintain that copper wire." Then the owner of the fiber could tell the cablecos the same thing; "Why bother with that coaxial cable? Just use my fiber." Then the owner of the fiber could offer the same proposition to Internet Service Providers, record labels, movie studios and anybody else with traffic that a home user might pay for. If the first fiber builder worked single-mindedly to aggregate all traffic, the way John D. Rockefeller worked to consolidate his hold on oil production, oil refineries, and oil transport, that fiber could form the basis for an insurmountable monopoly. The first builder of FTTH would have incredible market power, even if its fiber only covered a neighborhood or a few small towns. If a second fiber builder threatened, the first builder could simply lower prices to ensure that neither providers of downstream traffic nor end-user customers would switch. When John D. Rockefeller did this, he said he was giving nascent competition "a good sweating" [ibid, p. 42]. A more recent monopolist referred to such tactics as "cutting off [the competition's] air supply." The builder of the first FTTH could offer end-user connectivity that would not only be cheaper than a second fiber, but would also be cheaper, more reliable and more capacious than connectivity via twisted pair, coaxial cable, or radio waves. But to do that, the builder of the first fiber would need to be single-minded about co-opting other networks and carrying all available traffic. Like John D. Rockefeller, the owner of that first fiber would have to pay strict attention to costs. The Internet lowers costs because it is designed for reliable service over unreliable media. As a result, fiber allows simpler, lighter-weight protocols than telcos use. Fiber to the home can be built and lit today for between $600 and $3000 per customer. Maintenance is another cost factor; in the mid-1990s former Bell Atlantic CEO Ray Smith declared that fiber was so reliable that it beat copper on truck rolls alone, independently of any new business it might bring. Scale is a third factor; once right-of-way is acquired, ditches dug, et cetera, pulling 1000 fibers costs only a few percent more than pulling two. Once a fiber builder makes the decision to build at scale, there are solid reasons to believe that costs could drop well below $600 a home. Given the FCC's February 20, 2003 order (written to update FCC regulations enforcing the 1996 Telecom Act) that the ILECs need not unbundle nor share their FTTH with competitors, you might think that the telcos would rush to build FTTH. You might think they'd rush to co-opt complementary networks and carry additional traffic such as TV signals. You'd think they'd rush to lock in future monopoly access to the home. But they won't. I've seen telco culture up close. The telcos are no Standard Oil. The people running them are no John D. Rockefeller. If some future John D. Rockefeller got a job at a telco, he'd quit (or be fired). There's no room for vision or visionaries in patrimonial telco culture. No, unfortunately the telcos will not rush to lock in a future monopoly. Unlike John D. Rockefeller, the CEOs of telcoland are neither believers in, nor builders of the future of their business. They want to see fiber optic success first, before they build. Further, they'll never expand laterally. They were not promoted for their business acumen; they don't have the strategic ability to co-opt competitors or neighboring businesses. And finally, they'll want to build the old fashioned way, incrementally, with constraints on capacity, with complex (so-called) reliability mechanisms that will add to their costs. In addition, the telcos are too worried about the present to pay adequate attention to the future. Long-distance has been in precipitous decline for years. Cellular service revenues in the developed countries are maxing out. Now the number of local loops is declining and local service revenues are beginning to shrink as new ways to communicate encroach on telephony-classic. Even ILEC data revenues are hurting, despite the Internet-driven need for more DSL, T-1 and DS-3; according to Phil Jacobson and Farooq Hussain of Network Conceptions, LLC (http://www.netconllc.com) each of the ILECs recorded shrinking data revenues in at least one quarter of 2002. This is not cyclicity, it is the beginning the end of the vertical telephone company business model. It's even worse than that. The February 20, 2003 FCC order perpetuates high-cost telco incrementalism. The FCC says that it "elects not to unbundle bandwidth for the provision of broadband services for loops where incumbent LECs deploy fiber further into the neighborhood but short of the customer's home (hybrid loops) . . ." Telecom analyst and Former FCC staff member Kevin Werbach says that this incents the ILECs to install "Potemkin fiber" -- a single silly millimeter of fiber in the loop would protect the ILEC from unbundling. Telcos get this message; Scott Moritz at TheStreet.com reports that Verizon CEO Ivan Seidenberg says that Verizon's capital spending, which declined 30% in 2002 "may contract" further in the wake of the February 20 order. Instead of spurring a great new wave of telco investment, the FCC's February 20 order will spur ever more steeply declining telco revenues, a new wave of rear-guard litigation and lobbying, and a growing gap between what the technology makes possible and what the telcos actually deliver. There are several plausible incremental, non-monopolistic scenarios for how the market for Internet connectivity might evolve. For example, my former AT&T boss, Greg Blonder, advances a theorem in a provocative article in Barron's (Nov. 11, 2002, http://tinyurl.com/6hg0) to explain why today's telcos are not rushing to embrace FTTH. He observes that, "If new technologies promise improvements by a factor of more than four, they tend not to get funded because they are seen as too risky. And if they promise less than a factor of two, they tend not to get funded because they offer too little economic benefit." Fiber would have 30 million times the capacity of dial-up data when lit at the highest speeds allowed by today's commercially available technology. FTTH, lit at practical speeds, affordable for a few tens or hundreds or thousands of dollars, would offer 100 to 10,000 times dial-up speed. No wonder the telcos are not rushing to install FTTH. Blonder observes that the hybrid fiber-coax network of the cablecos provides a moderately fat pipe that is amenable to a series of 2x to 4x improvements. He projects that within a decade the current broadcast-based business model will disappear because all video will be video-over-Internet. From this, he reasons that cablecos are positioned to migrate from a broadcast model to a connectivity model. Supplementally, Blonder adds, cablecos could lay down a substantial footprint of aggregated wireless ((e.g., 802.11) hotspots. It is a plausible scenario, but I'm skeptical that cablecos (or *any* company) can successfully switch to a very different business model, especially when the new business model is perceived by current management as a threat to the old one. There's another plausible scenario for the incremental arrival of the next network -- primary radio connectivity. Several people, most notably David P. Reed, have observed that wireless networks can be architected so that their capacity can grow with the number of customers. Economics of such networks are quite attractive -- they require very little advance capital expenditure. Put up a base station, and after that you only need to spend build-money as customers are added. Because capex is tied directly to revenue growth, the network builder avoids the risky up- front capex that Blonder's theorem takes as given. If customers are willing to buy their own network infrastructure, today's fixed-wireless technology can offer up to 1000 times dial-up speeds. Reed also addresses the scalability of wireless networks. He proposes that the throughput and redundancy of a network grows without obvious limit when network nodes can relay packets that are addressed to other nodes. That is, every additional customer brings more additional network infrastructure than they themselves need. As Duncan Davidson, co-founder of relay-network equipment builder SkyPilot observes, "As a mesh gets dense, the links get shorter, speeds increase, power drops, reliability increases, line of sight goes away as an issue, and the radios get simpler and cheaper." It reminds me of the physical properties that drive Moore's Law. Reed calls it, "Cooperation gain" [http://tinyurl.com/6sgm/]. In theory, wireless relay networks could be completely user-owned; a service provider could be as free to add a competing gateway to such a network as any other participant (I dare not say customer). Networked nirvana is at hand! However, such concepts are still in research stages. Reed notes that Claude Shannon's seminal work on information theory was based on a single user, and that there is not yet a complete multi-station information theory. First work in that direction yields surprising and counter-intuitive results; Reed points out that relay-hopping is not the only thing that increases the capacity of a network. Multi-path transmission and motion increase capacity too. We are just beginning to explore packet relay systems. There are many real-world unknowns. The first such multi- hop network product, by Nokia Rooftop Networks, has not yet taken the world by storm. Nor have we yet observed how actual traffic behaves on such networks -- does it scale in well-behaved ways or are there emergent, unpredictable negative effects? In addition, we know that each station requires non-trivial antennas, transmitters, signal processing and computational logic that add to costs in ways that fiber does not. Even if these other scenarios were to become reality, an FTTH monopoly could disrupt and subsume them. Surely, somewhere on Earth, some budding monopolist, somebody who is not immunized by interests vested in current networked business models, could be attracted by the disruptive potential of FTTH -- tens of thousands of times dial-up capacity, or more, and growing. Once attracted, building a business would still be a difficult, non-obvious proposition. Getting the tactics right would be harder still. Actually doing it would require even more extraordinary business acumen, perhaps ruthlessly discriminatory pricing, or collusion with existing providers, or even willful disregard of the End-to-End Principle. It is likely that an FTTH monopoly would not be pretty. It could lead to decades of criminally culpable networked collusion. But t'ain't necessarily so. It might also be the fastest way for humanity to benefit from the technology we now have at hand. Back in the early 1980s at Mattel, we didn't understand Moore's Law and suffered the consequences -- Mattel's home computer, eighteen months in the making, was priced twice as high as it should have been. Then, as my colleagues and I began to understand Moore's Law, we'd project the cost curve towards $0.00 and say, "All the value's going to be in software -- but how do you make money from software?" It was not an easy question. Arguably, only one guy figured it out. He realized that his big chance hung on the fact that the first piece of software costs 100% of R&D, while copies 2 through N are virtually free. Today the biggest opportunity in information technology hangs on the fact that the capacity of FTTH is virtually unlimited. Who will be the Bill Gates, the Theodore Vail, the John D. Rockefeller of communications networks? The opportunity is there for the taking. Now we return you to our regularly scheduled program of aiding and abetting competition, deriding large clueless entities, and open-mouthed amazement at the wonders of today's communications technologies. ------- Quote of Note: Dick Cheney "There is a reason to believe that the threat level has increased somewhat. We see more noise in the system, more reporting that leads us to be cautious here." United States Vice-President Richard Cheney, May 22, 2002, in http://tinyurl.com/6ue5. ------- Quote of Note: Tom Ridge "I think we can anticipate more noise in the system, more threats, because of a potential invasion." Tom Ridge, Director of the U.S. Office of Homeland Security, in the New York Times, March 4, 2003, http://tinyurl.com/6u3d. ------- Quote of Note: Paul Wolfowitz "We have aggressive efforts underway to find new ways to discern terrorist 'signals' from the background 'noise' of society, but we must also recognize that enemies will deliberately create 'noise' in the system in order to conceal the real signals." U.S. Deputy Secretary of Defense Paul Wolfowitz, testifying before the U.S. Congress, September 19, 2002 http://tinyurl.com/6u42. ------- If it's Funny, it Must be True by Scatt Oddams Here's one from the right -- I mean from the 'toonists down at the CIA: http://tinyurl.com/6u13. This one's only funny if it's *not* true. And here's a bunch from the left -- I mean from those fine folks who take the pledge seriously to preserve, protect and defend the U.S. Constitution: http://tinyurl.com/4bw5. Gotta go, Dave! Scatt ------- CONFERENCES ON MY CALENDAR March 31 through April 3, 2003, San Jose CA. VON. I am organizing a panel on April 1 (5:00 to 6:15 PM) with Tim Horan of CIBC, Roxane "smarter-than-your-average-bear" Googin, and Anders Comstedt, the fellow who built the profitable, profitable, profitable, profitable, profitable, dark fiber network in Stockholm. April 1 is one of my favorite holidays. You will believe EVERYTHING my panel presents -- http://www.von.com/ April 22-25, 2003, Santa Clara CA. O'Reilly Emerging Technology Conference. My presentation will be called Operating Models for Stupid Networks, Friday, April 25 at 2:00 PM -- http://tinyurl.com/4yhe. June 11-14, 2002, Philadelphia PA. TedMed3. Come if you possibly can. http://tedmed.com. ------- COPYRIGHT NOTICE: Redistribution of this document, or any part of it, is permitted for non-commercial purposes, provided that the two lines below are reproduced with it: Copyright 2003 by David S. Isenberg isen@isen.com -- http://isen.com/ -- 1-888-isen-com ------- [There are two ways to join the SMART List, which gets you the SMART Letter by email, weeks before it goes up on the isen.com web site. The PREFERRED METHOD is to click on http://isen.com/SMARTreqScript.html and supply the info as indicated. The alternative method is to send a brief, PERSONAL statement to isen@isen.com (put "SMART" in the Subject field) saying who you are, what you do, maybe who you work for, maybe how you see your work connecting to mine, and why you are interested in joining the SMART List.] [to quit the SMART List, send a brief "unsubscribe" message to isen@isen.com] [for past SMART Letters, see http://www.isen.com/archives/index.html] [Policy on reader contributions: Write to me. I won't quote you without your explicitly stated permission. If you're writing to me for inclusion in the SMART Letter, *please* say so. I'll probably edit your writing for brevity and clarity. If you ask for anonymity, you'll get it. ] *--------------------isen.com----------------------* David S. Isenberg isen@isen.com isen.com, inc. 888-isen-com http://isen.com/ 203-661-4798 *--------------------isen.com----------------------* -- The brains behind the Stupid Network -- *--------------------isen.com----------------------*